Paul Volcker is the giant among
contemporary central bankers, both literally and figuratively. He it was who
had the moral courage to crush inflation as chairman of the Federal Reserve
between 1979 and 1987. When Mr Volcker speaks, people listen. What he had to
tell the economic club of New York last month was well worth listening to. His
summation, cited above, was so devastating, because so true.
Mr Volcker noted that this crisis
is not unique. On the contrary, “today’s financial crisis is the culmination,
as I count them, of at least five serious breakdowns of systemic significance
in the past 25 years – on the average one every five years. Warning enough that
something rather basic is amiss.” Those who do not heed such warnings are fated
to suffer something yet worse.
So what is to be done? There is a
part of me – quite a large part, in fact – that says: “Forget regulation: it
will never work. Apart from normal laws against fraud, let the financial system
live and die by the laws of competitive markets. If businesses fail, let them
simply go down, with all their shareholders, customers and employees.
Meanwhile, we will remind users constantly of the dangers.”
I suspect this approach might
give us a better financial system than the one we have today. But it is one we
cannot have because governments will not dare let us, as experience with
Northern Rock and Bear Stearns has reminded us. The public, governments feel,
must be protected from banks and banks must be protected from themselves.
Finance is deemed far too important to be left to the market.
Given this, regulation will need
to be radically reconsidered, unless, as Mr Volker points out, we are
comfortable with a substantial financial crisis every five years or so. However
great the lobbying power of the financial sector, it will surely be unable to
preserve a licence to commit havoc on such a scale, particularly when, as he
also remarks, “it is hard to argue that the new system has brought exceptional
benefits to the economy generally”.
So far tighter regulation is
desirable in the longer-run interests of the industry itself, let alone the
public’s. What, then, should such regulation look like? Here I would like to
analyse what I see as the fundamental issues. I am influenced in doing so by an
excellent recent paper* from Nouriel Roubini of New York University’s Stern
Business School.
So here are seven principles of
regulation. I call them the seven “Cs”.
First, coverage. Perhaps the most
obvious lesson is the dangers of regulatory arbitrage: if the rules required
certain capital requirements, institutions shifted activities into
off-balance-sheet vehicles; if rules operated restrictively in one
jurisdiction, activities were shifted elsewhere; and if certain institutions
were more tightly regulated, then activities shifted to others. Regulatory coverage
must be complete. All leveraged institutions above a certain size must be
inside the net. Second,
cushions. Equity capital is the most important cushion in the financial system.
Also helpful is subordinated debt. If Bear Stearns had had larger equity
capital, the authorities might not have needed to rescue it. Capital
requirements must be the same across the entire financial system, against any
given class of risks. But there must also be greater attention to the adequacy
of that other cushion: liquidity.
Second, cushions. Equity capital
is the most important cushion in the financial system. Also helpful is
subordinated debt. If Bear Stearns had had larger equity capital, the
authorities might not have needed to rescue it. Capital requirements must be
the same across the entire financial system, against any given class of risks.
But there must also be greater attention to the adequacy of that other cushion:
liquidity.
Third, commitment. The
originate-and-distribute model has, it is now clear, a huge drawback:
originators do not care sufficiently about the quality of loans they plan to
offload on to others. They do not, in Warren Buffett’s phrase, have “skin in
the game”. That makes for sloppy, if not irresponsible or even fraudulent
lending. Originators should be required, therefore, to hold equity portions of
securitised loans.
Fourth, cyclicality. Existing
rules are pro-cyclical. Capital evaporates in bad times, as a result of
write-offs, thereby forcing contraction of lending, worsening the economic
slowdown and further impairing assets. Mark-to-market accounting, though
inherently desirable, has a similar effect. One solution could be to
differentiate between target levels of capital and a lower minimum level.
Institutions that have minimum capital in bad times would only be required to
aim for the higher target level over an extended period.
Fifth, clarity. Lack of
information, asymmetric information and uncertainty are inherent in financial
activities. These are why they are vulnerable to swings in collective mood. The
transactions-orientated financial system is particularly vulnerable, because
information has to flow freely across arms-length markets. So a big challenge
is to generate as much clarity as is possible. One issue is the calamitous
recent role of the rating agencies and the conflicts of interest under which
they operate.
Sixth, complexity. Excessive
complexity is a significant source of lack of clarity. It is particularly
damaging, as we have seen, to the originate-and-distribute model, because
markets in complex securitised products may, at times, seize up, forcing
central banks to become “market makers of last resort”, with all the
difficulties this entails. One possibility then is to insist that all
derivatives be traded on exchanges.
Seventh, compensation. On this I
can do no better than quote Mr Volcker: “In the name of properly aligning
incentives, there are enormous rewards for successful trades and for loan
originators. The mantra of aligning incentives seems to be lost in the failure
to impose symmetrical losses – or frequently any loss at all – when failures
ensue.” Whether regulators can do anything effective is unclear. That this is a
challenge is not.
John Maynard Keynes wrote of an eighth “c”. He argued that “when the capital development of a country becomes a byproduct of the activities of a casino, the job is likely to be ill done”. He had a point. Features of a casino will always be present in a financial system that performs the essential functions of guarding people’s savings and allocating them where they can do most good. Regulation will always be highly imperfect. But an effort must still be made to improve it. |
|部落|Archiver|手机版|英文巴士
( 渝ICP备10012431号-2 )
GMT+8, 2016-5-14 16:12 , Processed in 0.061221 second(s), 11 queries , Gzip On, Redis On.